Introduction
In order to
tax land values, the value of the land has first to be assessed. In any system of Land Value Taxation (LVT), the way in which land
values are assessed will be of critical importance to taxpayer and Government
alike. From the taxpayer’s point of
view, the method of valuation should be logical, transparently clear and
fair. From the Government’s point of
view, the tax base should be stable and the revenue from it predictable.
In this paper, we consider the key principles in valuing for the purposes of Land Value Taxation.
Capital or rental values
The value of
land can be expressed in two ways – what it would fetch if sold, i.e., its
capital (market) value, and what it would rent for, i.e., its annual rental
value. For the reasons explained in this
paper, it is important that LVT be levied on the annual rental value and not on
the capital or market value.
At first
sight, this seems odd, even perverse.
Apart from farmland, bare land is rarely, if ever, rented. There is little or no evidence of land rents. On the other hand, building land is constantly
being bought and sold and it is not difficult to find good objective evidence
for capital values. The problem with
capital values, however, is that they are subject to the vagaries and
vicissitudes of market sentiment and can fluctuate considerably. The yield of LVT based on capital values is
likely to vary considerably. This lack
of stability and predictability in the market makes the capital value basis
unsatisfactory from the Government’s point of view. It is also unsatisfactory from the taxpayer’s
point of view, as the tax he has to pay may well fluctuate from year to year.
If rents are
fairly stable and land values reflect rental values, why should land values be
unstable? One obvious reason is interest
rates. Land prices are very sensitive to
interest rate movements given that most land transactions are financed by
borrowing. It is not just actual
interest rate movements which are relevant here, but the expectation of
interest rate changes. Land prices are
also subject to speculative surges. When
these over-reach themselves, land prices can fall dramatically. It would be inappropriate to import this
frothy overlay into the LVT valuation base.
It would be a serious error, therefore, to base LVT on capital
values. Annual rental values alone can
meet the necessary requirements for stability and fairness.
Assessing the annual rental value of land
If bare land
(other than farmland) is hardly, if ever, rented, how can land rental values be
assessed with confidence? If annual rental
values cannot be assessed with confidence, how can they meet the criteria of
fairness and transparency?
Although
land is hardly ever rented on its own, it is constantly rented with a building
on it. The rent of a property, i.e.,
land and building, therefore has two components – the rent of the land and the
rent of the building. In this country
there is an efficient market in the rental of all categories of land and
buildings, i.e., commercial, retail, industrial and residential. The annual rent for all these types of
property can be assessed with confidence.
The question then is: does there exist a sound technique for assessing
how much of the rent is attributable to the building and how much is
attributable to the land? It is argued
here that there exists a proven and acceptable technique for doing just this.
By way of
illustration, take the case of a newly built three-bedroomed house with garden
in a suburban South Eastern location.
Its sale value is £300,000. The
house cost £150,000 to build including the builder’s normal development
profit. It follows that the balance of
£150,000 – half of the total - must be attributable to the site. If the rent is £1,000 a month, i.e., £12,000
per annum, it is fair and reasonable to impute half of this to the land. The annual rent for LVT purposes would
therefore be £6,000, i.e., half of £12,000.
The
relationship of land to buildings – 50:50 in the above example – will vary
across the country and even within a particular locality. In the North, for example, the land element
in property values will tend to be lower.
In very depressed areas it could even be close to zero. By the same token, in particular areas of the
South East, e.g., Central London, land values may well account for considerably
more than 50% of property value, perhaps even as much as 80% or more.
Most
properties are not new and many in fact are very old. As any home owner knows to his cost, a
building deteriorates with time and requires increasing maintenance. This should be taken into account on a
depreciated replacement cost basis in allocating the property value between
land and buildings. Admittedly, working
out the depreciated replacement cost of a property requires skill and experience
but this task is well within the competence of surveyors and valuers. Done as a matter of routine in an LVT
environment, the technique would be refined and standardised across the
country, thus ensuring consistency and fairness.
The land rent
thus assessed would properly be described as an imputed or attributed
rent. This technique of imputing a land
rent from the property rent would account for the vast majority of land value
assessments whether it concerned industrial, commercial, retail or residential
land. There would nevertheless be
instances where this technique would not be applicable or where it would
require modification. Obvious areas
where special arrangements will be needed include parkland and open spaces,
churches, schools and hospitals. It
would be out of place in a paper of this general nature to detail these special
arrangements.
Property (i.e., land and building) rents
In view of
the above, the way in which property (i.e., land and buildings) rents are
assessed is clearly of prime importance.
What is sought is the open market rent (i.e. the annual amount that it is
reasonable to suppose the property in question would rent for if
advertised in the normal way). This is a
task which is carried out all the time by chartered surveyors and estate agents
across the country. The process takes
into account the age and condition of the property, its location and
suitability for its purpose. The annual
rental is then assessed by reference to the rental being paid on comparable
properties, taking into account differences between the subject property and
the comparable properties.
In coming to
an assessment of the annual rent, the valuer would naturally have to take into
account all relevant factors (i.e. factors which affect the rent including
location and planning permission, actual or potential). This would be a matter of professional
judgement on the part of the valuer. It
would be a mistake to hem the valuer in by specifying relevant or non-relevant
factors. There would be one exception to
this rule. In assessing the market rent
for the property, it should be assumed that the tenant has the right to renew
the lease (at the then market rent) indefinitely.
It would be
vital for the credibility – and, hence, acceptability – of any LVT scheme for
there to be regular and frequent periodic valuations. Valuations under the current rating system
are done every five years. As LVT would
be a far more significant impost than local rates, valuations would have to be
updated at least every three years. The
aim should be to achieve even greater frequency.
Land rental
value assessments would be subject to appeal by the taxpayer. In the case of an appeal the valuer would
have to justify the rental assessment and show the evidence of market rents on
which the value has been based. Annual
rents that cannot be justified by reference to market evidence cannot stand.
As with any
new tax there are bound to be circumstances not envisaged by the initial
legislation. This will no doubt be the
case with LVT. However, as regards
valuation, the generation schema set out in this paper should provide a
feasible framework.
Copyright (c) Coalition for Economic Justice, November 2010